From Casetext: Smarter Legal Research

Doehler Metal Furniture Co. v. United States

Circuit Court of Appeals, Second Circuit
Apr 26, 1945
149 F.2d 130 (2d Cir. 1945)

Summary

In Doehler Metal Furniture Co. v. United States, 149 F.2d 130, 133 (2d Cir. 1945), the Second Circuit held that the addition of a liquidated damages clause in the re-let contract did not bring the case under Axman.

Summary of this case from Seaboard Lumber Company v. U.S.

Opinion

No. 287.

April 26, 1945.

Appeal from the United States District Court for the Southern District of New York.

Action by the Doehler Metal Furniture Company, Inc. against the United States of America to recover on a contract for sale by plaintiff to defendant of furniture wherein defendant filed a counterclaim. From a summary judgment dismissing the complaint entered by the United States District Court for the Southern District of New York, the plaintiff appeals, and from so much of the judgment as disallowed a portion of defendant's counterclaim, the defendant also appeals.

Reversed and remanded.

On December 22, 1938, plaintiff, Doehler Metal Furniture Company, Inc., entered into a contract with defendant, the United States of America, for the sale by Doehler to the defendant of 6,141 pieces of steel furniture (to be manufactured by Doehler) for the use of the army in the Canal Zone, at a price of $92,391.80 less a discount of 1% for payment within ten days after delivery, which delivery was to be made on or before April 12, 1939. Article 5 of the contract provided in part:

"Article 5. Delays — Damages. If the contractor refuses or fails to make deliveries of the materials or supplies within the time specified in Article 1, or any extension thereof, the Government may by written notice terminate the right of the contractor to proceed with deliveries or such part or parts thereof as to which there has been delay. In such event, the Government may purchase similar materials or supplies in the open market or secure the manufacture and delivery of the materials and supplies by contract or otherwise, and the contractor and his sureties shall be liable to the Government for any excess cost occasioned the Government thereby * * *."

Doehler having failed to make delivery of any of the furniture, the government, by telegram dated April 17, 1939, confirmed by a letter of April 19, notified Doehler that "pursuant to article five * * * your right to proceed is hereby terminated" as to 5,464 pieces of the furniture but directing Doehler to "expedite performance" as to the balance, or 677 pieces; the letter stated that the purchase of the 5,464 pieces had been made in the open market and that the difference in cost would be charged to Doehler. On May 31, Doehler delivered to the government the 677 pieces; it was subsequently agreed by the parties that the amount due therefor was $8,860.11. On April 18, the government, after soliciting bids, had made a contract with the lowest bidder, Equipment Furniture Corporation, for delivery, on or before May 29, 1939, of the 5,464 pieces at price of $105,057.90, less 1% discount for payment within ten days. In all other respects the contract was the same as that with Doehler except that there was substituted for Article 5 a provision for liquidated damages which, so far as here pertinent, reads as follows:

"Article * * * Delays — Liquidated Damages. If the contractor refuses or fails to make delivery of the materials or supplies within the time specified in Article 1, or any extension thereof, the actual damage to the Government for the delay will be impossible to determine, and in lieu thereof the contractor shall pay to the Government, as fixed, agreed, and liquidated damages for each calendar day of delay in making delivery, the amount as set forth in the specified or accompanying papers, and the contractor and his sureties shall be liable for the amount thereof; Provided, however, That the Government reserves the right to terminate the right of the contractor to proceed with deliveries or such part or parts thereof as to which there has been delay, and to purchase similar material or supplies in the open market or secure the manufacture and delivery thereof by contract or otherwise, charging against the contractor and his sureties any excess cost occasioned the Government thereby, together with liquidated damages accruing until such time as the Government may reasonably procure similar material or supplies elsewhere * * *."

The government having made prompt payment to Equipment, received a 1% discount. Deducting (1) this discount, (2) the $8,860.11 and (3) a few small items not necessary to mention here, the government asserted that the cost for the 5,644 pieces delivered under this contract exceeded the price under the Doehler contract by $21,682.42. Against this amount the government credited Doehler with the $8,860.11 and certain other small items, leaving a net amount due the Government of $12,711.85. Because of delays on the part of Equipment, the government collected from it $9,119.75 in liquidated damages, pursuant to the above liquidated damage clause.

The computation is as follows:
Cost of 5,464 pieces from Equipment ........... $105,057.90 Less 1% discount .............................. 1,050.58 ___________ $104,007.32 Plus additional inspection costs .............. 282.87 ___________ Cost from Equipment ........................... $104,290.19 Cost of 5,464 pieces under Doehler contract ... 83,442.19 Less 1% discount .............................. 834.42 ___________ Cost from Doehler ............................. 82,607.77 ___________ Excess Cost ................................... $ 21,682.42 Credit to Doehler For the 677 pieces ......................... 8,860.11 Other Items ................................ 110.46 ___________ Total Credit to Doehler ....................... 8,970.57 ___________ Net Amount owing to government ......... $ 12,711.85

The government having refused to pay the $8,860.11, Doehler brought this suit therefor in the court below. The government counterclaimed for $12,711.85. Both parties moved for summary judgment. The trial court denied Doehler's motion and entered judgment dismissing Doehler's complaint but awarding the government $3,612.10, that being the $12,711.85 excess cost minus the $9,119.75 (received as liquidated damages from Equipment) plus $20 costs. Doehler has appealed from the judgment; the government has also appealed, assigning as error the failure to include in the judgment the sum of $9,119.75.

Gresser Walker, of New York City (Nathan Walker, of New York City, on the brief), for plaintiff-appellee-appellant.

John F.X. McGohey, of New York City (John F. Ryan, of New York City, of counsel), for defendant-appellant-appellee.

Before L. HAND, CHASE and FRANK, Circuit Judges.


1. Since Doehler was in default as to delivery of all the furniture covered by the contract, the government had the privilege, conferred by the reletting provision, to refuse to accept delivery in toto and to let a new contract for the 6,321 pieces, holding Doehler for the "excess cost." Doehler contends that the government could not exercise that privilege as to reletting with respect to part of the furniture, while calling on Doehler to deliver the balance, and that therefore Doehler cannot be held liable pursuant to the reletting provision. In effect, the argument is that, by its conduct, the government abandoned its rights under that provision. That contention is untenable. The government's voluntary relinquishment of a portion of its privilege was not an abandonment of the rest of it. Although we do not so decide, we may assume, arguendo, that Doehler might properly have refused to deliver the 677 pieces; but even if it were true that, in that respect, the government sought to deviate from the terms of the contract conferring the privilege, that fact would not invalidate the exercise of that privilege as to the 5,644 pieces.

We may arrive at the same conclusion by another route: If we assume that the attempted exercise of the privilege, because partial, was invalid, then the notice of April 17-18 was an offer to Doehler by the government to exercise that privilege in part and to receive delivery from Doehler of the 677 pieces; assuming further that Doehler could properly have refused that offer and that, had it done so, the government, by reletting a contract for only 5,644 pieces, would have lost its rights under the reletting provision, the fact is that Doehler did not refuse but, on May 31, some six weeks after the notice, delivered the 677 pieces; accordingly, whatever Doehler's legal position might otherwise have been, it is surely now in no position to object to the enforcement of the reletting provision as to the 5,644 pieces.

2. Doehler contends that the inclusion in the Equipment contract of the liquidated damage clause wiped out Doehler's liability for "excess cost" under the reletting provision, regardless of whether or not, in fact, that inclusion caused all or part of the increased price under the Equipment contract. For, argues Doehler, the addition of that clause was a material change which "affected the price as a matter of law." This alleged doctrine (reminiscent, in its rigid formality, of the rule in Shelley's case) finds no support in the cases; those cited by Doehler related to relet contracts calling for performance of work of a kind substantially different from that which the first contractor had agreed to perform or for the delivery of goods of a substantially different character.

United States v. Axman, 234 U.S. 36, 34 S.Ct. 736, 58 L.Ed. 1198; Rosenberg v. United States, 76 Ct.Cl. 662. Doehler makes no point of the fact that the government's notice said that the goods had been procured in the open market whereas in fact the government procured them by a second contract; we therefore do not consider that point except to note that it probably lacks substance.

The addition, however, of the liquidated damage clause may in fact have accounted, to some extent or entirely, for the increased price named in the Equipment contract. Doehler argues that Equipment must have known that the government could never prove any precise amount of damages caused by delay; and that, therefore, Equipment, recognizing that the added clause increased its risk, should it delay in making delivery, must be "conclusively presumed" to have demanded that its contract included a promise of extra compensation for taking that risk. But that argument impliedly rests on the axiom that businessmen invariably recognize the risks they take and always nicely calculate them in dollars and cents. Doubtless at one time many economists, believing it to be self-evidently true that every man is solely a fanatically rational "economic man," accepted that axiom as virtually a law of nature; but, as the result of accurate observation of human behavior, that axiom is now generally treated as an assumption to be used most cautiously with full awareness that it is a "neglective fiction." Courts use such (and other) fictions; but this particular fiction should surely not be the basis of a "conclusive presumption" or otherwise serve as a substitute for evidence.

J.M. Clark, employing what he calls "non-Euclidean economics," suggests as an axiom or postulate that most businessmen do not act with rational foresight, and that a competitive system is possible only because most of them do not intelligently pursue their own self-interest. He refers to the "fanatically economic man," and says, "The consistent economic man has long been known to be a sheer abstraction, though not every one has realized the importance of the elements left out." See Clark, A Preface to Social Economics (1936) 32, 36, 120 note, 126.
As to "neglective fictions," see Vaihinger, The Philosophy of "As If" (transl. 1925) 19-25, 79-80, 109-110, 131, 184-196. Cohen and Nagel, Logic and Scientific Method (1934) 372-375, present a somewhat more moderate view of such devices: "Various fallacies result from the inadequate realization of the metaphorical character of many propositions and of the symbolical nature of all language. Words are counters or symbols, and it would be a grave error to identify a symbol with what it stands for or represents. Indeed, all thinking proceeds by noting certain distinguishable features in things, symbolizing such selected features by appropriate counters, and then reasoning upon such abstracted features by means of the symbols. In dealing intellectually with some concrete, specific situation, we do not pay attention to all the infinitely complex relations which it has, or to all of its qualities. On the contrary, we neglect almost all of the qualities and relations which a thing has, and note only those features which enable us to view that thing as an instance or example of indefinitely repeatable patterns or types of situations. Thus our knowledge of things involves abstraction from the infinitely complex and perhaps unique properties which situations have * * *. Through this process of abstraction we develop the notions of limiting ideal patterns of structure and behavior. We thus arrive at the concepts of a perfectly straight line, of a frictionless surface, of a pure economic motive, of a rigid body, and so on, each of which represents a phase of some situation or other, but none of which can be identified with the whole concrete nature of anything. It is a serious and widespread error, however, to suppose that because the objects of all discursive thinking are selected abstract phases of things, and not things in their concrete undifferentiated totality, that therefore science is fallacious and fictional. For we should realize that the abstract objects of thought such as 'numbers,' 'laws,' 'perfectly straight lines,' and so on are real parts of nature (even though they do not exist as particular things, but as the relations or transformations of such particulars). Because numbers or ratios are abstractions it does not follow that there is anything fictional in the assertion that the earth has 'one' moon, or that the 'rate' of infant mortality has recently decreased. The contrary supposition arises from a false notion of scientific procedure and its results. It arises from forgetting that abstractions are real parts, phases, or elements in things or their relations, even though they are not identical in all respects with the things. * * * The fact that certain elements always occur in conjunction with others, and never in isolation is no more an argument against their reality than the fact that no one can be a brother or a creditor without being other things is an argument against the possibility of having these abstract characteristics. Science must abstract some elements and neglect others, because not all things that exist together are relevant to each other. Hence there is no fiction in talking about purely economic motives if we remember, as Adam Smith surely did, that in actual life these are associated with other motives. If we recognize the reality of abstractions, then there is nothing fictional (in the sense of false) about perfectly straight or circular lines, perfectly free bodies, frictionless engines, and other entities which seem imaginary and indeed are known to be incapable of separate existence. For the relation of distance between things exists in nature where the things are and is independent of the thickness of cord or chain by which we measure it. * * * Another way of looking at neglective fictions such as perfectly rigid bodies, perfect distribution, and the like is to view them as ideal limits. No one thing in nature corresponds to these, but things do differ in degrees of rigidity or homogeneity, and may be arranged into series according to the degree of rigidity or homogeneity they possess. Perfect rigidity would then be the character which all the members of the series possessed in some degree, and on the basis of which they are ordered in the series. It is the principle of order of such a series. If there is no inherent fiction in abstraction, there is none in scientific 'construction' out of such elements, as, for example, a typical vertebrate animal, a typical river valley or factory as an economic unit, an ideal government under limited conditions. * * * Fictions, like maps and charts, are useful precisely because they do not copy the whole but only the significant relations. These relations are identical in analogous cases; and we perceive and master the flux of phenomena only when we see running through it the threads of identity." For another approach, by a student of language, see Bloomfield, Linguistic Aspects of Science, International Encyclopedia of Unified Science, Vol. I, No. 4 (1939) 36-38, 40.

Moreover, we would indulge in the sheerest guessing if we were to say that Equipment must necessarily have regarded the added clause as appreciably augmenting its risk; for the contract, even without that clause, would have subjected Equipment, if it delayed, to the consequences of the relet provision with a possibility of its liability for increased costs, a possibility which, in wartime conditions, might easily have become a strong probability. Besides, as Doehler (somewhat inconsistently) says in its brief, Equipment, when it made its contract, "may have been so sanguine of ability to perform in time as to make any delay damage seem unimportant."

Whether, then, and to what extent, the added clause affected the price named in the Equipment contract are questions of fact which cannot be answered on the basis of the data before us or before the trial judge when he gave summary judgment for the government. There must be a trial on those issues.

With respect to those issues, we think that the burden of proof must be on the government. Had the second contract, except as to price, been the same in terms as the first, the price named in the second contract would be assumed to be reasonable, absent any contrary evidence. But such an assumption is unwarranted in the light of the additional clause. We cannot say that there is a strong probability that that clause did not raise the price; nor is it true that the facts are more accessible to Doehler than to the government; nor are there any policy grounds for not letting the burden rest where it ordinarily would rest, i.e., on the government, which, under the counterclaim, is asserting a claim against Doehler.

United States v. McMullen, 222 U.S. 460, 471, 32 S.Ct. 128, 56 L.Ed. 269.

If, at the trial it should be proved that the added clause explains the entire difference between the prices in the two contracts, then the government's counterclaim must fail. Should it appear, however, that the added clause increased the price only in part, then the counterclaim will not wholly fail but will merely be reduced by the amount of such partial increase. For the situation here is not like that which exists when the government, in a purported reletting, contracts for work or goods substantially different from that covered by the original contract; in such a case, the government cannot recover under the reletting provision for the reason that, the two contracts being incommensurable, the price named in the second contract "cannot be used for the measure of recovery for breach of the original contract." The attempted comparison is then like one between pigs and apples. But where the goods to be delivered under the two contracts are precisely the same and the only difference is an added item of obligation which enhances the cost in an ascertainable amount, the comparison, once the cost of that item is deducted from the price in the second contract, is unimpeachable. Consider, for instance, a contract for Idaho potatoes to be delivered at St. Louis followed by a relet contract, at a greater price, which requires delivery at Cleveland, where part of the increase in price can be shown to be due to additional transportation charges.

United States v. Axman, 234 U.S. 36, 41, 42, 34 S.Ct. 736, 58 L.Ed. 1198; United States v. United States Fidelity Co., 236 U.S. 512, 522, 35 S.Ct. 298, 59 L.Ed. 696; California Bridge Co. v. United States, 245 U.S. 337, 344-345, 38 S.Ct. 91, 62 L.Ed. 332. We need not here consider whether the government having chosen to proceed under the reletting provision has made an election and is therefore precluded from asking for damages to which, as a buyer whose seller has defaulted, it would be entitled at "common law." As to whether the damages recoverable under the reletting provision differ from those at "common law" and as to whether seeking relief under that provision is an election, cf. United States v. United States Fidelity Co., 236 U.S. 512, 516, 522-524, 526, 35 S.Ct. 298, 59 L.Ed. 696.

We take this occasion to suggest that trial judges should exercise great care in granting motions for summary judgment. A litigant has a right to a trial where there is the slightest doubt as to the facts, and a denial of that right is reviewable; but refusal to grant a summary judgment is not reviewable. Such a judgment, wisely used, is a praiseworthy time-saving device. But, although prompt despatch of judicial business is a virtue, it is neither the sole nor the primary purpose for which courts have been established. Denial of a trial on disputed facts is worse than delay. Cf. Arenas v. United States, 322 U.S. 419, 429, 433, 64 S.Ct. 1090, 88 L.Ed. 1363. The district courts would do well to note that time has often been lost by reversals of summary judgments improperly entered. Sartor v. Arkansas Natural Gas Corporation, 321 U.S. 620, 624, 64 S.Ct. 724, 88 L.Ed. 967, tells us that, especially where, as here, damages are in question, the courts should go slow about making haste by a summary judgment; there the Supreme Court said that "at least a summary disposition of issues of damage should be on evidence which a jury would not be at liberty to disbelieve and which would require a directed verdict for the moving party." Of course this court will respect, as a precedent, the recent ruling on that subject in Madeirense Do Brasil, S/A v. Stulman-Emrick Lumber Co., 2 Cir., 147 F.2d 399, 405; but the judges sitting in the instant case think that that ruling, because of the peculiar atypical facts of the Madeirense case, should not be generously applied.

See, e.g., Arenas v. United States, 322 U.S. 419, 64 S.Ct. 1090, 88 L.Ed. 1363; Sartor v. Arkansas Natural Gas Corporation, 321 U.S. 620, 64 S.Ct. 724, 88 L.Ed. 967; Cohen v. Eleven West 42nd Street, 2 Cir., 115 F.2d 531, 532; Whitaker v. Coleman, 5 Cir., 115 F.2d 305, 306; McElwain v. Wickwire Spencer Steel Co., 2 Cir., 126 F.2d 210, 211; Weisser v. Mursam Shoe Corporation, 2 Cir., 127 F.2d 344, 346, 145 A.L.R. 467; Toebelman v. Missouri-Kansas Pipe Line Co., 3 Cir., 130 F.2d 1016, 1018; General Accident etc. v. Goodyear Tire Rubber Co., 2 Cir., 132 F.2d 122, 125; Walling v. Fairmont Creamery Co., 8 Cir., 139 F.2d 318; Walling v. Reid, 8 Cir., 139 F.2d 323; M. Snower Co. v. United States, 7 Cir., 140 F.2d 367.

Cf. Shientag, Summary Judgment (1941) 20.

3. Both the contract with Doehler and that with Equipment provided for a discount of 1% of the contract price for payment within ten days. The government paid Equipment for the 5,644 pieces within the ten days and deducted the 1% in the amount of $1,050. In computing the excess cost, the government reduced the purchase price of the 5,644 pieces under the Doehler contract, by deducting 1% of the purchase price, i.e., $834.42, and the trial judge accepted that method of computation. Doehler asserts that, in this respect, he erred, contending that the $834.42 was improperly deducted and that the counterclaim, if valid, should be reduced by that amount; for, says Doehler, the discount was to be given for prompt payment and no payment has been made to it for those pieces. But that contention neglects the fact that the Equipment contract was, in part, a substitute for the Doehler contract, and that prompt payment to Equipment with its resultant discount, reduced the "excess cost" by $1,050, thus benefitting Doehler; not to reduce the Doehler contract price equivalent in effect would be to give Doehler that benefit twice.

4. Doehler, in its pleadings, set up payment as an alternative defense to the counterclaim. In support of this defense, it filed an affidavit stating that, under a distinct contract of May 24, 1940, relating to the sale of articles not covered by the December 1938 contract, the government owed it $11,531.67 which had not been paid, and that, if the counterclaim is valid, this sum, withheld by the government, constitutes payment of the counterclaim. The trial judge did not consider this issue which also presents a question of fact to be dealt with at the trial.

5. The government, on its appeal, complains that the trial judge held that the government's counterclaim must be reduced by $9,119.75, i.e., the amount collected as liquidated damages from Equipment. We think the trial court erred, for the following reasons: Suppose that the contract with Equipment had contained no liquidated damage clause. Then the "excess cost" for which Doehler would have been liable to the government would have included not only (1) the increase in the contract price but also (2) the damages caused by Equipment's delay in delivery; for the words "excess cost" are broader than "increase in contract price." If, in those circumstances, the government by suit against Equipment had collected a sum for damages caused by its delay, it could not also have recovered that amount from Doehler. But that amount, representing such delay damages, could not properly have been applied in reduction of the other item of Doehler's liability, i.e., its liability for the increase in the contract price. The situation here must yield a similar result: The amount collected as liquidated damages from Equipment precludes recovery of that amount from Doehler on account of Equipment's delay. But that amount may not be deducted from that part of the claim against Doehler constituting the increase in the contract price. However, there should be such a deduction to the extent that the amount collected as liquidated damages does not represent actual damages caused by Equipment's delay, since that amount, if any, in fact reduced the government's cost.

In its brief, Doehler arrives at the same conclusion but on a different ground. Doehler says: "Obviously, the liquidated damage clause in the re-let contract was to liquidate damages 'for delay.' Although no such clause is to be found in the Doehler contract, it cannot be denied that under its contract Doehler was liable for damages 'for delay.' However, Doehler's liability was not liquidated. It was implied in law, and was to be measured by proof of actual damages cognizable under general law. * * * Thus we have demonstrated that Doehler was impliedly liable for actual damages for delay in addition to its express liability for excess cost." (Italics added.)

We need not consider whether the government may recover from Doehler for Equipment's delay to the extent that actual damages resulting from that delay exceed the liquidated damages received from Equipment.

An alternative approach to this problem leads to the same conclusion: Let us assume that the "excess cost" for which Doehler is liable does not include any actual loss from Equipment's delay. Then, ex hypothesi, that loss is not part of the government's "cost" (which must be taken into account in computing the "excess cost") but is an additional item of loss for which the government had a right to be reimbursed by Equipment. However, to the extent that the liquidated damages collected from Equipment exceed that item of actual loss, the excess must be regarded as reducing the contract price paid to Equipment.

We are left then with this problem: Must Doehler prove that, in whole or part, the liquidated damages paid by Equipment were greater than the actual delay damages caused by Equipment or must the government prove that they were not? We think that, for the following reason, the task is Doehler's: We may suppose, as an extreme case (but one which does not exhaust the category), an express understanding between the government and Equipment by which Equipment paid the liquidated damages as a concealed means of reducing its contract price. Such a supposititious case supplies us with the rationale: The reason for crediting Doehler with all or part of the liquidated damages must be that otherwise the government would be unjustly enriched, at Doehler's expense, by receiving more than the "excess cost." But, absent proof, such unjust enrichment should not be assumed to be a fact. We know that the government may be seriously damaged in incalculable ways through delay in receipt of goods in wartime; we have recently held that a liquidated damages clause in a government wartime contract is not to be easily defeated for the very reason that only with great difficulty, if at all, could the government show the quantum of its loss. United States v. Walkof, 2 Cir., 144 F.2d 75, 77. Such would have been our ruling if the government had sued Equipment for the liquidated damages. It would be most unfair, then, to say, that, in litigation with Doehler, the government must be deemed to have suffered an actual loss less than the liquidated damages unless it can prove the contrary. And here, where we have no precedent to guide us, we must decide on the basis of policy, governed by what seems to us to be fair.

Morrison v. California, 291 U.S. 82, 91, 54 S.Ct. 281, 78 L.Ed. 664; Webre Steib Co. v. Commissioner, 65 S.Ct. 578, 581; United States v. District Director of Immigration, 2 Cir., 106 F.2d 14, 21; Thayer, Preliminary Treatise On Evidence (1898) 318-319, 327, 331; Wigmore, Evidence (3d ed.) § 2486; Bohlen, The Effect of Rebuttable Presumptions of Law Upon The Burden of Proof, 68 Un. of Pa.L.Rev. (1920) 307, 310, 311, 313, 319, 321; Morgan, Some Observations Concerning Presumptions, 44 Harv.L.Rev. (1931) 906, 909, 910-911, 926, 928, 930-934; Morgan, Instructing The Jury Upon Presumptions and Burden of Proof, 47 Harv.L.Rev. (1933) 59, 77; Rustad v. Great Northern R. Co., 122 Minn. 453, 122 N.W. 727, 728; Lisbon v. Lyman, 49 N.H. 553, 566.
Mr. Justice Holmes often called attention to policy (or what he called "legislative considerations") as influencing the development of judicially made legal rules. See, e.g., the following writings by Holmes: Common Carriers and The Common Law, 13 Am.L.Rev. (1879) 609, 630-631; The Common Law (1881) 1, 5, 35-36, 68, 116, 204-205; The Path of The Law, 10 Harv.L.Rev. (1897) 457, 466-467; Frankfurter, The Early Writings of O.W. Holmes, Jr., 44 Harv.L. Rev. (1931) 717, 719, 774, 779, 781 note, 791; Vegelahn v. Guntner, 167 Mass. 92, 104, 106, 44 N.E. 1077, 35 L.R.A. 722, 57 Am.St.Rep. 443; Hudson County Water Co. v. McCarter, 209 U.S. 349, 355, 28 S.Ct. 529, 52 L.Ed. 828, 14 Ann.Cas. 560.

Reversed and remanded.


I agree in all that my brothers say, except that I think that the defendant should be compelled in computing its damages, to deduct from what it paid to the Equipment Company so much of the amount which it set off as liquidated damages, as it cannot prove as actual damages for delay. I agree that the plaintiff is liable for all damages caused to the defendant by the delay of the Equipment Company; indeed, for all actual damages for delay in delivery of the goods after the time fixed for delivery in the plaintiff's contract until delivery by the Equipment Company; all such are part of its "proximate" damages. I cannot, however, see the relevance upon that issue of the contract between the defendant and the Equipment Company, which compromised in advance, as between them, the defendant's damages for delay. There can be no real doubt that the liquidated damages did not in fact correspond to anything that the defendant could have recovered from the plaintiff on that score. I do not forget that the defendant's actual losses may have been in fact as great as the liquidated damages — indeed, that possibility alone justified the clause — but the relevant question here is, not what was the defendant's actual loss, but what it could have recovered from the plaintiff in dollars and cents; an issue as to which the contract between the defendant and the Equipment Company is res inter alios acta. To allow the defendant to disregard what it set off is to allow it to charge the plaintiff with liquidated damages; and if the defendant wished so to increase the plaintiff's liability, the place, and the only place, was in the contract between the two.


Summaries of

Doehler Metal Furniture Co. v. United States

Circuit Court of Appeals, Second Circuit
Apr 26, 1945
149 F.2d 130 (2d Cir. 1945)

In Doehler Metal Furniture Co. v. United States, 149 F.2d 130, 133 (2d Cir. 1945), the Second Circuit held that the addition of a liquidated damages clause in the re-let contract did not bring the case under Axman.

Summary of this case from Seaboard Lumber Company v. U.S.

In Doehler Metal Furniture Co. v. United States, 149 F.2d 130, 135, 136, the Court of Appeals of the Second Circuit took occasion to suggest that trial judges exercise great care in granting motions for summary judgment, saying ‘ A litigant has a right to a trial where there is the slightest doubt as to the facts'.

Summary of this case from Lane v. Greyhound Corp.

In Doehler Metal Furniture Co. v. United States, 149 F.2d 130, 135, 136, the Court of Appeals of the Second Circuit took occasion to suggest that trial judges exercise great care in granting motions for summary judgment, saying "A litigant has a right to a trial where there is the slightest doubt as to the facts".

Summary of this case from Columbia Pictures Corp. v. Coomer

In Doehler Metal Furniture Co. v. United States, 2 Cir., 149 F.2d 130, 135, the Circuit Court in this Circuit said: 'We take this occasion to suggest that trial judges should exercise great care in granting motions for summary judgment.

Summary of this case from Hydraulic Press Mfg Co v. E W Bliss Co

In Doehler Metal Furniture Co. v. U.S., C.C.A.2d, 149 F.2d 130, 135, it is stated, "We take this occasion to suggest that trial judges should exercise great care in granting motions for summary judgment.

Summary of this case from Parman v. Petricciani
Case details for

Doehler Metal Furniture Co. v. United States

Case Details

Full title:DOEHLER METAL FURNITURE CO., Inc., v. UNITED STATES

Court:Circuit Court of Appeals, Second Circuit

Date published: Apr 26, 1945

Citations

149 F.2d 130 (2d Cir. 1945)

Citing Cases

Seaboard Lumber Company v. U.S.

The Eighth Circuit held to similar effect in American Surety Co. v. United States, 317 F.2d 652, 656-57 (8th…

Arnstein v. Porter

The answer depends on whether "there is the slightest doubt as to the facts." Doehler Metal Furniture Co. v.…